Economics.
Publié le 10/05/2013
Extrait du document
«
Malthus, nature's check was “positive”: “The power of population is so superior to the power of the earth to produce subsistence for man, that premature death must insome shape or other visit the human race.” The shapes it took included war, epidemics, pestilence and plague, human vices, and famine, all combining to level theworld's population with the world's food supply.
The only escape from population pressure and the horrors of the positive check was in voluntary limitation of population, not by contraception, rejected on religiousgrounds by Malthus, but by late marriage and, consequently, smaller families.
These pessimistic doctrines of classical economists earned for economics the epithet of the“dismal science.”
Mill's Principles of Political Economy was the leading text on the subject until the end of the 19th century.
Although Mill accepted the major theories of his classical predecessors, he held out more hope than did Ricardo and Malthus that the working class could be educated into rational limitation of their own numbers.
Mill was also areformer who was quite willing to tax inheritances heavily and even to allow government a larger role in protecting children and workers.
He was far more critical thanother classical economists of business behavior and favored worker ownership of factories.
Mill thus represents a bridge between classical laissez-faire economics and anemerging welfare state.
The classical economists also accepted Say's Law of Markets, the doctrine of the French economist Jean Baptiste Say.
Say's law holds that the danger of generalunemployment or “glut” in a competitive economy is negligible because supply tends to create its own matching demand up to the limit of human labor and the naturalresources available for production.
Each enlargement of output adds to the wages and other incomes that constitute the funds needed to purchase added output.
D Marxism
Opposition to the classical school of economics came first from early socialist writers such as the French social philosopher the comte de Saint-Simon and the Britishreformer Robert Owen.
It was Karl Marx, however, who provided the most important social theories.
To the classical vision of capitalism, Marxism was in large measure a sharp rebuttal, but to some extent it embodied variations of classical themes.
Marx adopted, forexample, a version of Ricardo's labor theory of value.
With a few qualifications, Ricardo had explained prices as the result of the different quantities of human laborneeded to produce different finished products.
Accordingly, if a shirt is priced at $12 and a pair of socks at $2, it is because six times as many hours of human laborentered into the making of the shirt as the socks.
For Ricardo, this theory of value was an analytical convenience, a way of making sense of the multitude of differentprices in shops.
For Marx, the labor theory was a clue to the inner workings of capitalism, the master key to the inequities and exploitation of an unjust system.
An exile from Germany, Marx spent most of his mature years in London, supported by his friend and collaborator, the German revolutionist Friedrich Engels, and by theproceeds from occasional contributions to newspapers.
He conducted his extensive research in the reading room of the British Museum.
Marx's historical studiesconvinced him that profit and other property income are the proceeds from force and fraud inflicted by the strong on the weak.
“Primitive accumulation” in English economic history was epitomized by the record of land enclosure.
In the 17th and 18th centuries, landowners used their control ofParliament to rob their tenants of traditional rights to common lands.
Taking these lands for their own use, they drove their victims reluctantly into cities and factories.
Deprived both of tools and land, British men, women, and children had to work for wages.
Thus, Marx's central conflict was between so-called capitalists who owned themeans of production—factories and machines—and workers or proletarians who possessed nothing but their bare hands.
Exploitation, the heart of Marxist doctrine, ismeasured by the capacity of capitalists to pay no more than subsistence wages to their employees and extract for themselves as profit (or surplus value) the differencebetween these wages and the selling price of market commodities.
Although in the Communist Manifesto (1848) Marx and Engels paid grudging tribute to the material achievements of capitalism, they were convinced that these were transitory and that the internal contradictions within capitalism would as surely terminate its existence as earlier in history feudalism had faltered and disappeared.
On this point Marx wrote not in the tradition of English classical economics but rather out of his training in the metaphysics of the German philosopher Georg WilhelmFriedrich Hegel.
Hegel interpreted the movement of human history and thought as a progression of triads: thesis, antithesis, and synthesis.
For example, a thesis mightbe a set of economic arrangements such as feudalism or capitalism.
Its opposite or antithesis was, say, socialism as opposed to capitalism.
The clash between thesis andantithesis evolved into the higher stage of synthesis—in this case communism, which unites capitalist technology with social public ownership of factories and farms.
In the long run, Marx believed that capitalism was certain to falter because its tendency to concentrate income and wealth in ever fewer hands created more and moresevere crises of excess output and rising unemployment.
For Marx, capitalism's fatal contradiction was between improving technological efficiency and the lack ofpurchasing power to buy what was produced in ever larger quantities.
According to Marx, the crises of capitalism were certain to manifest themselves in falling rates of profit, mounting hostility between workers and employers, and evermore severe depressions.
The outcome of class warfare was fated to be revolution and progress toward, first, socialism and ultimately communism.
In the first stage astrong state would still be required in order to eliminate the remnants of capitalist opposition.
Each person's work would be rewarded according to the value of his or hercontribution.
Once communism was achieved, the state, whose central purpose was class domination, would wither away, and each individual would in the utopianfuture be compensated according to need.
See Communism; Socialism.
E The Neoclassicists
Classical economics proceeded from the assumption of scarcity, such as the law of diminishing returns and Malthusian population doctrine.
Dating from the 1870s,neoclassicist economists such as William Stanley Jevons in Britain, Léon Walras in France, and Karl Menger in Austria shifted emphasis from limitations on supply tointerpretations of consumer choice in psychological terms.
Concentrating on the utility or satisfaction rendered by the last or marginal unit purchased, neoclassicistsexplained market prices not by reference to the differing quantities of human labor needed to produce assorted items, as in the theories of Ricardo and Marx, but ratheraccording to the intensity of consumer preference for one more unit of any given commodity.
The British economist Alfred Marshall, particularly in his masterly neoclassicist work Principles of Economics (1890), explained demand by the principle of marginal utility, and supply by the rule of marginal productivity (the cost of producing the last item of a given quantity).
In competitive markets, consumer preferences for low prices ofgoods and seller preferences for high prices were adjusted to some mutually agreeable level.
At any actual price, then, buyers were willing to purchase precisely thequantity of goods that sellers were prepared to offer.
As in markets for consumer goods, this same reconciliation between supply and demand occurred in markets for money and human labor.
In money markets, theinterest rate matched borrowers with lenders.
The borrowers expected to use their loans to earn profits larger than the interest they had to pay.
Savers, for their part,demanded a price for postponing the enjoyment of their own money.
A similar accommodation had to be made in wages paid for human labor.
In competitive labormarkets, wages actually paid represented at least the value to the employer of the output attributed to hours worked and at least acceptable compensation to theemployee for the tedium and fatigue of the work..
»
↓↓↓ APERÇU DU DOCUMENT ↓↓↓